Wednesday, May 21, 2008

Pleural Mesothelioma: Diagnosis


Your doctor may perform some of the following procedures to diagnose pleural mesothelioma.

CT scan

This type of X-ray provides a very detailed picture of the size and location of the cancer. The images taken are compiled by a computer to create a more complete image of the disease. The procedure is also called a computerized axial tomography (CAT) scan.

PET scan

A procedure in which a small amount of radioactive glucose (sugar) is injected into a vein, and a scanner is used to make detailed, computerized pictures of areas inside the body where the glucose is used. Because cancer cells often use more glucose than normal cells, the pictures can be used to find cancer cells in the body.

Thoracoscopy

The diagnosis of malignant pleural mesothelioma may involve your doctor looking inside the chest cavity with an instrument called a thoracoscope. For this procedure, an incision is made through the chest wall and the thoracoscope is put into the chest between two ribs. This procedure is usually done in the hospital.

Bronchoscopy

A bronchoscopy involves an examination of the lungs and air passages. The doctor places a lighted tube down the patient’s throat and trachea into the lungs. This procedure is called a bronchoscopy, and the instrument used is called a bronchoscope.

Thoracentesis

Some patients develop fluid in their lungs. This is called a pleural effusion. Your doctor might take a sample of this fluid with a needle injected into the chest and test the fluid for cancer cells. Your doctor may also perform this procedure for draining fluid from the lungs to help relieve pain.

Mediastinoscopy

This is a test that examines the mediastinum. This area is in the center of your chest, between your lungs, and contains the heart, blood vessels and lymph nodes.

Needle Biopsy

For this procedure, the doctor uses a thin needle to take samples of cells for examination under microscope. This test can be uncomfortable but may take only a few minutes. Small pieces of the tissue are taken and then sent to a laboratory for analysis.

The doctor might also use an X-ray, CT scan or fluoroscopy to guide the needle as it is inserted into the tumor. Fluoroscopy is a diagnostic procedure in which X-rays are passed through the body and then projected onto a screen, providing a continuous image of the body’s internal structures.

Wedge Biopsy

For this procedure, a doctor makes an incision through the skin, and a wedge of tissue or tumor is obtained and sent to a laboratory for analysis. A wedge biopsy is often used when other biopsy methods have been unable to confirm a diagnosis.

Cytology and Pathology

Pathology is a study of a disease, which looks at specific cells and types of a disease process to determine the cause. Pathology tests are performed on samples of body fluid or tissue to determine the cell type (cytology) of a specific disease. The process of looking at these samples may include using microscopes, electron microscopes and various stains. This refers to special cell-staining techniques that identify specific types of malignant mesothelioma tumors. Certain types of dyes or coloring are added to the patient’s biopsy samples. Depending on how the tissue responds to the dye, the doctor can make a better estimate about the outcome of the illness. In making the diagnosis, the more information the doctor has about the tumor, the better he or she can recommend appropriate treatment.

After your biopsy, a sample of the tissue or fluid removed may be sent to a hospital laboratory to be analyzed.

  • If fluid is removed during a thorancentesis or thorascopy, it is sent to a Cytology lab for analysis. Your doctor will receive a written report of the results. The doctor may receive an oral report from the lab prior to the written results.
  • If a tissue biopsy from a bronchoscopy, needle biopsy or thorascopy is done, it is sent to a surgical pathology lab for analysis. The final report will be sent to your doctor.
  • Surgical removal of a tumor, pleura or lung is sent to a surgical pathology lab. In the lab the material is analyzed with special stains. The material may be placed under a microscope for magnification and further review to determine the cell type. After analysis is completed, small pieces of any remaining tissue are preserved in paraffin for future us

Diagnosis



Diagnosis is the process of determining the kind of disease that is present. An accurate diagnosis is important because it helps to determine the type of treatment that you will undergo.

Your doctors may use a number of procedures to aid in the diagnosis of mesothelioma. The most common of those procedures are listed here. Whether one or a combination of these tests are conducted in a given patient’s case will depend on factors unique to the patient. Some tests might first be conducted to determine whether a biopsy should be performed. A biopsy is usually necessary to confirm a diagnosis.

For your reference, a word with “-scopy” at the end refers to the use of a scope or viewing instrument that can be used to look directly inside the body at the abnormal or suspected area. A word that ends in “-ectomy” refers to the removal of tissue through surgery.

Pleural Mesothelioma

Peritoneal Mesothelioma

Pericardial Mesothelioma


Symptoms of Mesothelioma



Mesothelioma is a form of cancer that develops in the lining around the lungs (the “pleura”), abdomen (the “peritoneum”), or heart (the “pericardium”).
Mesothelioma is almost always caused by exposure to asbestos. In contrast, lung cancer refers to a malignancy of the lung itself.

This section is not intended as a tool for self-diagnosis, nor is it intended to be a substitute for consulting with a doctor who specializes in the diagnosis and treatment of mesothelioma. This section is merely designed to help you learn about mesothelioma.

Pleural Mesothelioma

Pleural mesothelioma, also known as mesothelioma of the pleura, is a tumor of the lining surrounding the lungs. The pleura is a thin tissue around the lungs and the inside of the chest. In order to protect the lungs, the pleura produces a small amount of fluid which helps cushion the lungs, making the lungs move more smoothly during breathing.

Benign (Non-Cancerous) pleural mesothelioma

Benign pleural mesothelioma is a non-cancerous tumor that has not spread to other organs of the body. If the tumor is large, it may squeeze the lung itself and cause shortness of breath and pain.

Malignant Pleural Mesothelioma

Malignant Pleural mesothelioma is cancerous and can spread to other parts of the body. This rare form of cancer is found in the pleural sac lining of the lung. Exposure to asbestos is considered the primary cause of pleural mesothelioma.

Symptoms

Pleural mesothelioma may include shortness of breath, chest pain, back pain, pain in the rib cage, fluid build-up in the lung lining, hoarseness, coughing up blood, swelling of the face and arms, muscle weakness, paralysis and sensory loss.

Peritoneal Mesothelioma

Peritoneal mesothelioma, also known as cancer of the peritoneum, is a cancer of the abdominal lining.

One way doctors diagnose peritoneal mesothelioma is by looking inside the abdominal cavity with an instrument called a peritoneoscope. In this procedure, a cut is made through the abdomen wall and the peritoneoscope is placed into the abdomen. This test, called a peritoneoscopy, is usually performed in the hospital.

Some patients develop excessive fluid in the abdomen. This is called an effusion or ascites. A doctor may take a sample of such fluid to diagnose peritoneal mesothelioma. Fluid in the abdomen might also be drained to relieve symptoms of peritoneal mesothelioma. The procedure for drawing out this fluid is called “paracentesis”.

For more information about the diagnosis of this disease, click here

Symptoms

The symptoms of this cancer may include stomach pain, weight loss, nausea, vomiting, hernia, fluid in the abdominal cavity or a mass in the abdomen.

Pericardial Mesothelioma
Pericardial mesothelioma is also known as mesothelioma of the pericardium or cancer of the sac that holds the heart.

Your doctor may diagnose this cancer using a thoracoscope to perform a thoracoscopy, which might also involve opening up the chest cavity to remove the tumor.

Patients who develop excessive fluid around the heart, called an effusion, may have a sample of the fluid taken to diagnose pericardial mesothelioma. Fluid might also be drained to relieve symptoms of pericardial mesothelioma. The procedure for drawing out this fluid is called “pericardiocentesis.”

For more information about the diagnosis of this disease, click here.

Symptoms

Symptoms can include chest pain and shortness of breath. The tumor and/or fluid that accumulates between the heart and the sac can compress the heart, causing such symptoms

Mesothelioma and Lung Cancer

Pleural mesothelioma and lung cancer are both serious illnesses, but they are not the same. Pleural mesothelioma – sometimes called “asbestos lung cancer” – is really not a form of lung cancer, but a cancer of the lining that surrounds the lung.

A main difference between lung cancer and mesothelioma is that lung cancer is in the tissue of the lung. By contrast, pleural mesothelioma occurs in the lining around the lung.

Smoking is often considered a primary cause of lung cancer, while asbestos exposure is considered a primary cause of mesothelioma. Asbestos exposure may also be associated with lung cancer. Smoking is not linked to mesothelioma, however. Those exposed to asbestos and who smoke are as much as 90 times more likely to be develop lung cancer than those who don’t smoke.

Mesothelioma and Asbestos

Mesothelioma is a rare form of cancer caused by exposure to asbestos. Asbestos is a naturally-occurring fiber that, when released into the air, can be inhaled or swallowed. Asbestos has no smell or taste, and asbestos fibers are so small that they are not visible to the naked eye. Asbestos fibers can “stick” in the lung, abdomen and other body tissues and over time, lead to the development of asbestos-related diseases like mesothelioma. There is a long latency period between asbestos exposure and the development of mesothelioma; in other words, decades may pass after a person’s first exposure to asbestos before he or she becomes ill. A person who has been diagnosed with asbestosis (a non-cancerous scarring of the lungs) is at an increased risk of developing mesothelioma in the future.

Millions of people in the U.S. have been exposed to asbestos, and it is estimated that approximately 3,000 people are diagnosed with mesothelioma each year. In these pages, you will read about asbestos and the common ways in which people have been exposed to asbestos.


Pain Management

Here are some suggestions provided by www.cancer-pain.org to help you work effectively with your health care providers in assessing your pain:

  • Put it in writing. If possible, written notes about your pain (see Pain Diary, below) are valuable in giving accurate and comprehensive information.
  • Plan to ask questions. It’s important that you fully understand what your health care professional says to you about your pain. Ask questions until you are satisfied that you understand.
  • Have a notetaker. Sometimes it’s difficult to talk about your pain, ask questions and take notes on what’s being said to you all at the same time, especially if you are in pain. Bringing a friend or family member to take notes during the discussion about your pain can provide a valuable resource for you once the conversation has ended.
  • Make your views heard. Don’t hesitate to offer an opinion about what may be causing or contributing to your pain. No one knows your body as well as you, and your insights can be valuable to your health care providers.
  • These are points to consider as you prepare to discuss your pain and its management with your health care providers:
    • The location of all of your pains.
    • How the pain feels (use descriptive words such as dull, aching, throbbing, stabbing, piercing, pinching, sharp, aching, burning, tingling).
    • The intensity of your pain (when it is at its worst) and whether the intensity changes throughout the day and night.
    • When you have the pain (all the time or occasionally).
    • How quickly the pain comes on (suddenly or intermittently), how long it lasts (a few minutes or several hours), and how often it occurs.
    • What makes the pain worse? Describe conditions under which the pain becomes more intense, such as moving, walking, talking, coughing, laying down, eating, going to the bathroom, etc.
    • What eases the pain? Be ready to discuss anything that has helped you, including medication(s) you have been using, and the amounts you are taking.
  • Medications you are taking. Tell them about your pain medications, including any over-the-counter pain relievers, any alternative medications like herbs, and any medications you may be taking for other health conditions not related to cancer.
  • Side effects of your pain medications. Tell them what side effects you are experiencing, how the side effects are currently being treated, and if you are satisfied with this treatment.
  • Quality of life issues: What impact does the pain have on your quality of life? Can you work, enjoy your family and friends, eat and sleep well? If not, describe how the pain is limiting your activities. Also, tell your health care provider(s) what you want from pain management in terms of quality of life.
  • To keep an accurate record of what you are experiencing, consider creating a simple pain diary. You can do this in a notebook, recording information such as the date, time of day, level of pain you are feeling, what you did to remedy or alleviate it (i.e., medications taken, use of ice or heat, and so forth), and the outcome of your efforts to control the pain (Did the medication work? For how long? Were there side effects?)

Many health care professionals also use various “pain assessment scales” to record patients’ levels of pain. You can use this system, as well, in conversation with your health care provider. Make sure you always use the SAME scale when describing your pain, for consistency and clarity. One of the simplest involves describing your pain level in terms of numbers: “0″ means “no pain at all,” and “10″ means “the worst possible amount of pain.” The higher the number, the greater the pain. If your health care provider uses a different assessment measuring approach, you may want to use that one. Ask for an explanation of how she or he records patient pain levels.

Innovations in Treatment

Doctors and researchers are always on the lookout for new ways to treat malignant mesothelioma. The following innovations in treatment, while not a cure for malignant mesothelioma, show some promise in helping to treat the disease.

Alimta

Alimta, when given with another chemotherapy drug called cisplatin, is a chemotherapy drug recently approved by the FDA for the treatment of patients with malignant pleural mesothelioma.

Photodynamic Therapy

Photodynamic therapy uses special drugs and a special type of light to kill cancer cells during surgery. A drug that makes cancer cells more sensitive to light is injected into the patient’s vein several days before surgery. During surgery, a special light is used to locate the cancer. This treatment is being studied for early stages of malignant mesothelioma.

Immunotherapy

This type of treatment harnesses the power of the body’s own immune system. Immunotherapy is currently being researched as a treatment for malignant mesothelioma.

Gene Therapy

In studies of gene therapy for cancer, the goal is to improve the body’s natural ability to fight malignant mesothelioma directly or to make the cancer cells more sensitive to other kinds of therapy.

Brachytherapy

Brachytherapy is radiation therapy applied from within the body as opposed to from a machine outside the body. Radioactive sources are placed in or near the tumor, giving a high radiation dose to the tumor while reducing the radiation exposure in surrounding healthy tissues. This precision can help to minimize side effects.

Clinical Trials

A clinical trial (also clinical research) is a research study using human volunteers to answer specific health questions. Carefully conducted clinical trials help discover treatments that work in people and ways to improve health. Interventional trials determine whether experimental treatments or new ways of using known therapies are safe and effective under controlled environments. Observational trials address health issues in large groups of people or populations in natural settings. If you are interested in participating in a clinical trial, talk to your doctor about whether a clinical trial may be an appropriate option in your case.

Phase I

Phase I trials are considered the first step in testing the safety and efficacy of a new drug. Doctors and researchers are trying to determine many things about the drug’s effect on the disease and on the patient. Among the things that researchers are trying to determine are correct dosage, safety profile, and any side effects.

Phase II

At this stage, researchers select a relatively small group of patients to study the specific effects of the pre-determined dosage. Phase II studies also typically focus on a specific type of disease.

Phase III

During Phase III testing, researchers compare the effectiveness of the new, experimental drug against already existing therapies. Usually, patients are randomly assigned to therapeutic groups to cut down on the possibility of human bias. Phase III trials can be large, recruiting patients from across the country.
For more information about clinical trials, visit http://www.clinicaltrials.gov/ct/info/whatis

Radiation

Radiation therapy is an intense X-ray treatment to damage or kill cancer cells. Although not a cure for mesothelioma, radiation therapy nonetheless may be used at different stages of the disease to slow its growth. Radiation is often the main treatment for patients in weak health. Radiation is also used to destroy small clusters of cancer cells that may have been missed in surgery. When used in conjunction with surgery, radiation treatment is referred to as adjuvant radiation.

  • External Beam Radiation
    The form of radiation therapy used most often is external radiation, in which a machine very similar to an X-ray machine directs strong beams of light at the cancerous cells from outside the body, killing the tumor cells underneath.
  • Internal Radiation (Brachytherapy)
    Internal radiation therapy, also called brachytherapy, involves the placement of radiation sources in the body. With mesothelioma patients, the radioactive material is positioned inside the abdomen or the chest.

Supportive Care or Palliative Therapies

Palliative treatments refer to those procedures that relieve symptoms and help make the patient more comfortable. Here are some palliative therapies that may be used to treat mesothelioma.

  • Pleurodesis
    Pleurodesis is a procedure that is sometimes used to control pleural effusion, or the buildup of fluids between the lungs and the lung lining. Pleurodesis causes the space between the lungs and the lung lining to close, reducing the chance for fluid to accumulate. One method of pleurodesis uses thoracoscopy, whereby a small incision, or a few small incisions are made in the skin and a thoracoscope is passed through the incision to get a better look at the pleura. The sclerosing agent is then applied.
  • Pain Management
    Pain management is another way to treat the discomfort associated with mesothelioma. For additional information on pain management, please see Pain Management.

Chemotherapy


Chemotherapy uses certain chemical agents or drugs that are specifically destructive to malignant tissues and cells. Doctors may recommend single agent chemotherapy or a combination chemotherapy treatment. The single agent chemotherapy treatment involves the use one type of chemical or drug. The combination chemotherapy method involves the use of more than one chemical or drug. While it is not a cure for mesothelioma, chemotherapy treatment may slow the progression of the cancer. What follows is a partial listing of the chemotherapy treatments a doctor might recommend to treat mesothelioma:

  • Alimta (Pemetrexed)
    Alimta, when used with Cisplatin is indicated for treatment of malignant pleural mesothelioma and is usually given through an intravenous tube (IV infusion).
  • Onconase (Ranpirnase)
    A new drug that may help slow the growth of mesothelioma tumors.
  • Navelbine (Vinorelbine)
    Like Alimta, when combined with other drugs in chemotherapy, Navelbine is used to treat mesothelioma tumors. Clinical trials are still underway and testing on some patients has begun. Navelbine is usually given intravenously.
  • Carbonplatin (Paraplatin)
    A chemotherapy medication that interferes with the growth of cancer cells. It has been shown to slow the spread of cancer. Some serious side effects have been reported with the use of Carboplatin.
  • Cisplatin (Platinol)
    Cisplatin is a clear fluid given in combination with other drugs in the treatment of certain types of cancer, including mesothelioma. In treatment for mesothelioma, Cisplatin is usually administered with Alimta. As with many chemotherapy drugs, certain side effects may occur. Cisplatin is usually given by IV infusion.
  • Related Drugs and Therapy
    Besides the chemotherapy drugs doctors prescribe for the treatment of malignant mesothelioma, there are other drugs intended for post-chemotherapy use. Doctors will also prescribe drugs intended for use at the same time chemotherapy or radiation is underway, that are meant to minimize the side effects that can accompany these treatments.
    • Taxotere, Taxol
      Tumors can return after chemotherapy in some cases. Taxotere and Taxol are drugs that are used to help rid the body of cancer cells when cancer recurs following a previous chemotherapy treatment. These drugs inhibit the duplication or reproduction of cancerous cells. They are delivered through intravenous infusion.
    • Zofran and Anti Nausea Drugs
      One of the most common side effects of chemotherapy treatment is nausea. Zofran is a drug used to ease nausea. Others are Emeset, Oncoden and Zofron. These drugs can help to control radiation therapy induced nausea, as well as post-op nausea and other kinds of nausea.
    • Endostatin
      A natural protein shown to inhibit the growth of blood vessels. The administration of Endostatin results in cancerous tumors “starving” due to lack of blood. This drug is still in clinical trials and has not been approved for general prescription, however.

Surgery

In some cases, surgery may be indicated to alleviate symptoms or slow the progression of mesothelioma. Surgery may be performed in tandem with other treatments such as chemotherapy and radiation, also known as “multi-modal therapy.”

Whether a surgery is recommended in your case will depend on factors unique to your situation, including the type and location of the cancer, the “stage” of the cancer, and your overall health. Of course, whether your doctor recommends surgery in your case will depend on factors individual to your case.

Pleural Mesothelioma Surgeries

Thoracentesis

This procedure involves the draining of fluid that may build up (called a “pleural effusion”) in the chest between the lung and the pleura. A tube is placed in the chest in order to drain out the fluid. Thoracentesis is a “palliative” treatment, meaning that its purpose is to help relieve discomfort.

Pleurodesis

Pleurodesis is a surgical procedure to help control pleural effusion, which is the buildup of fluid between the lungs and the lung lining. Pleurodesis closes the space between the lung and the lung lining, reducing the chance for fluid to accumulate.
There are two approaches to performing a pleurodesis. In the first, a tube that is inserted into the chest drains the excess fluid. After this fluid is drained, a schlerosing agent (a substance that causes tissue to scar or harden), such as sterile talc powder, is injected through the chest tube and into the pleural space. The schlerosing agent is allowed to distribute itself through the pleural space, with the patient being asked to move about in order to facilitate the distribution. Once the agent is distributed, suction is applied to the tube in the chest. Similar to collapsing a plastic bag, the suction brings the two pleural surfaces together, allowing them to “scar” together.

The second method of pleurodesis uses thoracoscopy, whereby a small incision, or a series of small incisions, are made in the skin. A thoracoscope is passed through the incision in order to get a better look at the pleura. The schlerosing agent is then applied to the area.

Pleurectomy/Decortication

Pleurectomy/decortication involves removing the pleura, where most of the tumor is located. This procedure may help control pleural effusions (fluid build-up) and help to decrease the pain caused by the tumor. It is a palliative treatment, meaning that its goal is to help to lessen the discomfort caused by mesothelioma.

Pneumonectomy

A pneumonectomy is the removal of all or part of the lung. Your surgeon will make an incision in the side of the chest. When the lung is revealed, the surgeon visually assesses the tumor and decides how much tissue should be removed.

Extrapleural pneumonectomy

This extensive surgery usually involves the removal of the pleura, pericardium, diaphragm, and the whole lung on the side of the cancerous tumor. Your surgeon may decide to remove some of the surrounding tissues, as well.

Peritoneal Mesothelioma Surgeries

Paracentesis

Peritoneal mesothelioma can cause fluid to build up in the abdomen in a process called peritoneal effusion. This excess fluid is drained through a needle and tube inserted into the abdomen. Paracentesis (sometimes called an “ascitic tap”) can help take the pressure off the internal organs, and also helps reduce the risk of infection that may be caused by the fluid buildup. This is a “palliative” procedure, meaning that the goal of paracentesis is to help to relieve the discomfort associated with peritoneal mesothelioma.

Peritonectomy

A “peritonectomy” involves removing the peritoneum, the lining of the abdomen where the mesothelioma first develops. This form of surgery is most often used when the cancer is detected in the very early stages of the disease. Your surgeon might recommend that a peritonectomy be performed in tandem with “intraperitoneal hypothermic perfusion,” a form of heated chemotherapy where the chemotherapy drugs are administered directly into the abdomen during and/or after surgery.

Cytoreductive (or “debulking”) surgery

During cytoreductive or debulking surgery, the surgeon opens the abdominal cavity (a procedure known as a “laparotomy”) to look for all signs of cancer and attempt to remove as much of the tumor as possible. This surgery can be quite long in duration because of the amount of detail the surgeon must use to search for and remove signs of cancer in the abdominal area. Your surgeon might recommend that this surgery be performed in tandem with “intraperitoneal hypothermic perfusion,” a form of heated chemotherapy administered into the abdominal cavity.

Pericardial Mesothelioma Surgeries

Pericardiocentesis

This is the process for drawing fluid out of the affected area to help to relieve the discomfort associated with pericardial mesothelioma. For this procedure, a needle is inserted into the pericardium (the sac around the heart) to drain the fluid and relieve circulatory problems. The draining of this fluid can be associated with complications, however.

Extrapleural pneumonectomy

An aggressive surgery also used in appropriate situations to treat pleural mesothelioma, an extrapleural pneumonectomy involves removal of the pleura, diaphragm, pericardium, and the entire lung on the side of the tumor.

Treatment

Here is a description of treatments for mesothelioma that a doctor may recommend. Whether a treatment is recommended depends on factors individual to each case. Though there is no known cure for the disease, these treatments can help to make the patient more comfortable or help to slow the progression of mesothelioma.

Surgery

Chemotherapy

Radiation

Supportive Care or Palliative Therapies

Innovations in Treatment

Pericardial Mesothelioma: Diagnosis


Pericardial mesothelioma is also known as mesothelioma of the pericardium or cancer of the sac that holds the heart. Your doctor may diagnose pericardial mesothelioma using a thoracoscope to perform a thoracoscopy, which might also involve opening up the chest cavity to remove the tumor.

Patients who develop excessive fluid around the heart, called an effusion, may have a sample of the fluid taken to diagnose pericardial mesothelioma.

Peritoneal Mesothelioma: Diagnosis



One way doctors diagnose peritoneal mesothelioma is by looking inside the abdominal cavity with an instrument called a peritoneoscope. In this procedure, a cut is made through the abdomen wall and the peritoneoscope is placed into the abdomen. This test, called a peritoneoscopy, is usually performed in the hospital. Some patients develop excessive fluid in the abdomen. This is called an effusion or ascites. A doctor may take a sample of such fluid to diagnose peritoneal mesothelioma.

Sunday, May 18, 2008

Health economics


Health economics is a branch of economics concerned with issues related to scarcity in the allocation of health and health care.

Four factors that are important to Health Economics: Government Intervention, Uncertainty, Asymmetric Knowledge, and Externalities.[1] Governments tend to heavily regulate the Healthcare industry and also tend to be the largest payor within the market. Uncertainty is intrinsic to health, both in patient outcomes and financial concerns. The knowledge gap that exists between a physician and a patient creates a situation of distinct advantage for the physician, which is called Asymmetric Knowledge. Finally, there are many effects that happen between two parties without monetary compensation, called externalities, within healthcare, from catching a cold from someone to practicing safe sex.

The scope of health economics is neatly encapsulated by Alan William's "plumbing diagram"[2] dividing the discipline into eight distinct topics:

  • what influences health? (other than health care)
  • what is health and what is its value
  • the demand for health care
  • the supply of health care
  • micro-economic evaluation at treatment level
  • market equilibrium
  • evaluation at whole system level; and,
  • planning, budgeting and monitoring mechanisms.

What influences health? Health of a country or the residence of that country is greatly dependent not only on the geographic location but the legal and economic stabilities of the nation. With healthcare industry having such a major impact on the economy of a nation(roughly 10%), it becomes the indispensable attention of all governments.

A stable legal policy not only aids in the on time improvement of the industry but its impact on the society as well.The exclusive government body focussed on the industry enhances the research and development along with the underpinning infrastructure required.

What is health and what is its value?

  • Private goods
  • Public goods
  • Merit goods

Health care demand

The demand for health care is a derived demand from the demand for health, more generally. Health care is demanded as a means for consumers to achieve a larger stock of "health capital." The demand for health is unique, because individuals allocate resources in order to both consume and produce health.

Michael Grossman's 1972 model of health production has been extremely influential in this field of study and has several unique elements that make it notable. The model views each individual as both a producer and a consumer of health, as measured in "health stock" or health capital, the flow of which is known as health status. It acknowledges that health care is both a consumption good that yields direct satisfaction and utility, and an investment good, which yields satisfaction to consumers indirectly (more productive, fewer sick days, higher wages, etc.) Since individuals in this model demand health care only as a result of their desire to increase their health stock, health care demand is a derived demand. The model takes into account health production (investments in health such as time spent exercising, money spent on medical care, etc.) as well as the production of non-health goods against the overall utility that results from ones investments. These factors are used to determine the optimal level of health that an individual will demand, taking into account the marginal cost of health capital and depreciation rates.

The optimal level of investment in health occurs where the marginal cost of health capital is equal to the marginal benefit resulting from it (MC=MB). With the passing of time, health depreciates at some rate δ. The general interest rate in the economy is denoted by r. The marginal cost of health capital can be found by adding these variables: MC_{HK}=r+\delta\,. The marginal benefit of health capital is the rate of return from this capital in both market and non-market sectors. In this model, the optimal health stock can be impacted by factors like age, wages and education. As an example, \delta\, increases with age, so it becomes more and more costly to attain the same level of health capital or health stock as one ages. Age also decreases the marginal benefit of health stock. The optimal health stock will therefore decrease as one ages.[3]

When studying Health Care, it is beneficial to reference the fundamental laws of Supply and Demand. Health Care, just like anything else, is a finite resource. This is to say, Health Care is a scarce resource - whether one lives in a society in which Health Care is privitized or publicized. In either scenario, demand for Health Care will be high. Logically, demand will increase more if Health Care is made a Public Good (see Universal Health Care). There are positives and negatives to such a system. The most obvious positive is the fact that everyone can receive care.

However, what also must be noted is the fact that Universal Health Care will cause a spike in the Demand for it. Being a scarce resource, sacrifices are usually made. This is the main reason why there can be such long waits in a public Health Care system - quality health care is diverted to those who can afford to wait in line the longest.

This is not to say that a privatized Health Care policy does not have its flaws. Health insurance in the United States is largely a case of market failure. A large reason for this is asymmetrical information. Someone applying for health insurance knows more about their health than the insurance company does (see adverse selection and moral hazard). People who have health care may act more recklessly than if they didn't have it resulting in higher costs for the insurance company. Someone who applies for health insurance as an individual will usually pay higher rates than group plans for an equal level of insurance. Statistically, people who apply individually are more likely to need health care than those with group plans. Healthy people can't get health care via a group plan are more likely to go without any insurance at all. The higher rates for individuals and the low risk of a healthy person needing medical treatment that costs more than their deductible makes insurance more expensive than its worth. Thus individuals are perceived as more risky, individual plans are made more expensive and the rate of healthy people falls further as they decide that it isn't worth the expense.

The supply of health care

Micro-economic evaluation at treatment level

A large focus of health economics, particularly in the UK, is the microeconomic evaluation of individual treatments. In the UK, the National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence (NICE) appraises certain new and existing pharmaceuticals and devices using economic evaluation.

Economic evaluation is the comparison of two or more alternative courses of action in terms of both their costs and consequences (Drummond et al.). Economists usually distinguish several types of economic evaluation, differing in how consequences are measured:

  • Cost minimisation analysis
  • Cost benefit analysis
  • Cost-effectiveness analysis
  • Cost-utility analysis

In cost minimisation analysis (CMA), the effectiveness of the comparators in question must be proven to be equivalent. The 'cost-effective' comparator is simply the one which costs less (as it achieves the same outcome). In cost-benefit analysis (CBA), costs and benefits are both valued in cash terms. Cost effectiveness analysis (CEA) measures outcomes in 'natural units', such as mmHg, symptom free days, life years gained. Finally cost-utility analysis (CUA) measures outcomes in a composite metric of both length and quality of life, the Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY). (Note there is some international variation in the precise definitions of each type of analysis).

A final approach which is sometimes classed an economic evaluation is a cost of illness study. This is not a true economic evaluation as it does not compare the costs and outcomes of alternative courses of action. Instead, it attempts to measure all the costs associated with a particular disease or condition. These will include direct costs (where money actually changes hands, e.g. health service use, patient co-payments and out of pocket expenses), indirect costs (the value of lost productivity from time off work due to illness), and intangible costs (the 'disvalue' to an individual of pain and suffering). (Note specific definitions in health economics may vary slightly from other branches of economics.)

Market equilibrium

Health care markets

The five health markets typically analyzed are:

  • Healthcare financing market
  • Physician and nurses services market
  • Institutional services market
  • Input factors market
  • Professional education market

Although assumptions of textbook models of economic markets apply reasonably well to health care markets, there are important deviations. Insurance markets rely on risk pools, in which relatively healthy enrollees subsidize the care of the rest. Insurers must cope with "adverse selection" which occurs when they are unable to fully predict the medical expenses of enrollees; adverse selection can destroy the risk pool. Features of insurance markets, such as group purchases and preexisting condition exclusions are meant to cope with adverse selection.

Insured patients are naturally less concerned about health care costs than they would if they paid the full price of care. The resulting "moral hazard" drives up costs, as shown by the famous RAND Health Insurance Experiment. Insurers use several techniques to limit the costs of moral hazard, including imposing copayments on patients and limiting physician incentives to provide costly care. Insurers often compete by their choice of service offerings, cost sharing requirements, and limitations on physicians.

Consumers in health care markets often suffer from a lack of adequate information about what services they need to buy and which providers offer the best value proposition. Health economists have documented a problem with "supplier induced demand", whereby providers base treatment recommendations on economic, rather than medical criteria. Researchers have also documented substantial "practice variations", whereby the treatment a patient receives depends as much on which doctor they visit as it does on their condition. Both private insurers and government payers use a variety of controls on service availability to rein in inducement and practice variations.

The U.S. health care market has relied extensively on competition to control costs and improve quality. Critics question whether problems with adverse selection, moral hazard, information asymmetries, demand inducement, and practice variations can be addressed by private markets. Competition has fostered reductions in prices, but consolidation by providers and, to a lesser extent, insurers, has tempered this effect.

Competitive equilibrium in the five health markets

While the nature of healthcare as a private good is preserved in the last three markets, market failures occur in the financing and delivery markets due to two reasons: (1) Perfect information about price products is not a viable assumption (2) Various barriers of entry exist in the financing markets (i.e. monopoly formations in the insurance industry)

Ideological bias in the debate about the financing and delivery health markets

The healthcare debate in public policy is often informed by ideology and not sound economic theory. Often, politicians subscribe to a moral order system or belief about the role of governments in public life that guides biases towards provision of healthcare as well. The ideological spectrum spans: individual savings accounts and catastrophic coverage, tax credit or voucher programs combined with group purchasing arrangements, and expansions of public-sector health insurance. These approaches are advocated by health care conservatives, moderates and liberals, respectively.

Saturday, May 17, 2008

Health care politics


Health care often accounts for one of the largest areas of spending for both governments and individuals all over the world, and as such it is surrounded by controversy. Though there are many topics involved in health care politics, most can be categorized as either philosophical or economic. Philosophical debates center around questions about individual rights and government authority while economic topics include how to maximize the quality of health care and minimize costs.

Background

The modern concept of health care involves access to medical professionals from various fields as well as medical technologies such as medication and surgical techniques. One way that a person gains access to these goods and services is by paying for them. Now, many governments around the world have established universal health care, which essentially puts every person in a country on the same level of access.

Right to Health Care

The United Nations' Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR) asserts that medical care is a right of all people. Many religions also impose an obligation on their followers to care for those in less favourable circumstances, including the sick. Humanists too would assert the same obligation and the right has been enshrined in many other ways too.[1] [2]

An opposing school of thought rejects this notion.[3] They (laissez-faire capitalists for example) assert that providing health care funded by taxes is immoral because it is a form of legalized robbery, denying the right to dispose of one's own income at one's own will. They assert that doctors should not be servants of their patients but rather they should be regarded as traders, like everyone else in a free society."[4]

Government Regulation

A second question concerns the effect government involvement would have. One concern is that the right to privacy between doctors and patients could be eroded if governments demand power to oversee health of citizens.[5] In practice, this does not happen to any significant extent.

Another concern is that governments use legislation to control personal freedoms. For example, some Canadian provinces have outlawed private medical insurance from competing with the national social insurance systems for basic health care to ensure fair allocation of national resources irrespective of personal wealth. Laissez-faire supporters argue that this blocks a fundamental freedom to use one's own purchasing power at will.

Controlling the Industry

When a government controls the health care industry, they essentially mandate what health care everyone will get and use wealth redistribution to finance it, as with any tax. Critics would argue that HMOs and medical insurance companies (which are not under the democratic control of health care users) also determine what health care a person might get.

Universal health care requires government involvement and oversight.

Impact on quality of health care

One question that is often brought up is whether publicly-funded health care provides better or worse quality health care than market driven medicine. There are many arguments on both sides of the issue.

Arguments which see publicly-funded health care as improving the quality of health care:

  • For those people who would otherwise go without care, any quality care is an improvement.[citation needed]
  • Since people perceive universal health care as free, they are more likely to seek preventative care which makes them better off in the long run.[7]
  • A study of hospitals in Canada found that death rates are lower in private not-for-profit hospitals than in private for-profit hospitals.[8]

Arguments which see publicly-funded health care as worsening the quality of health care:

  • It slows down innovation and inhibits new technologies from being developed and utilized. This simply means that medical technologies are less likely to be researched and manufactured, and technologies that are available are less likely to be used.[9]
  • Free healthcare can lead to overuse of medical services, and hence raise overall cost.[10] [11]
  • Publicly-funded medicine leads to greater inefficiencies and inequalities. [12][3][13]
  • Uninsured citizens can simply pay for their health care. Even indigent citizens can still receive emergency care from alternative sources such as non-profit organizations.[citation needed] Some providers may be required to provide some emergency services regardless of insured status or ability to pay, as with the Emergency Medical Treatment and Active Labor Act in the United States.

Impact on medical professionals

Proponents of universal health care contend that universal health care reduces the amount of paperwork that medical professionals have to deal with, allowing them to concentrate on treating patients.

Opponents argue that government-mandated procedures reduce doctor flexibility. This, along with the loss of private practice options and possible reduced pay dissuades many would-be doctors from pursuing the profession.[citation needed]

Impact on Medical Research

Those in favor of universal health care posit that removing profit as a motive will increase the rate of medical innovation.] Those opposed argue that it will do the opposite, for the same reason.

Economic Impact

Universal health care affects economies differently than private health care.

Those in favor of universal health care contend that it reduces wastefulness in the delivery of health care by adding a middle man, the government, to regulate the supply of health care.[citation needed] For example, it might only take one government agent to do the job of two health insurance agents.

Those opposed to universal health care argue that socialized medicine suffers from the same financial problems as any other government planned economy. They argue that it requires governments to greatly increase taxes as costs rise year over year. Their claim is that universal health care essentially tries to do the economically impossible. Opponents of universal health care argue that government agencies are less efficient due to bureaucracy. However, supporters note that modern industrial countries with socialized medicine tend to spend much less on health care than similar countries lacking such systems, and their health outcomes are often significantly better.[citation needed]

In the United States, opponents of universal health care also claim that, before heavy regulation of the health care and insurance industries, doctor visits to the elderly, and free care or low cost care to impoverished patients were common, and that governments effectively regulated this form of charity out of existence. They suggest that universal health care plans will add more inefficiency to the medical system through additional bureaucratic oversight and paperwork, which will lead to fewer doctor patient visits. However, in the UK for example, which has universal health care under a socialized medicine arrangement, free home visits are common for the elderly and infirm that cannot visit a doctor's office and such visits are part of the service and are not offered as charity.[citation needed]

  • Healthy people who take care of themselves have to pay for the burden of those who smoke, are obese, etc.[citation needed] However, several countries tax alcohol and tobacco highly in order to recoup the costs that excessive use of these products has on national health expenditures. Some have even considered taxing more heavily foodstuffs that are considered less healthy[citation needed].
  • Opponents of single payer insurance programs claim that empirical evidence demonstrates that the cost exceeds the expectations of advocates.

Means

Many forms of universal health care have been proposed. These include mandatory health insurance requirements, complete capitalization of health care, and single payer systems among others.

Health care industry


Health care industry

Health care is one of the most rapidly growing sectors of the economy, with expenditures in 1988 totaling $539.9 billion, or 11.1 percent of GNP, up from 5.3 percent of GNP in 1960. For 1992, health care spending was projected to be over 13 percent of GNP. [Editor's note: this article was written in 1992.] This amounts to $2,124 per capita, of which $1,882 was for personal health care—medical services and supplies for individuals. The rest was for research, construction, administration, and public health activities. Hospital expenditures accounted for 39 percent of the total spent for personal health care, physician services for 19 percent, nursing home care for 8 percent, and other personal health care for 22 percent.

Is Health Care Different?

Health care differs from other goods and services in important ways. The output of a shoe factory is shoes. But the output of the health care industry is less well defined. It is unpredictable and imperfectly understood by producers, and still less by consumers. Also, third-party payment and government intervention are pervasive. None of these characteristics is unique to health care, but their extent and their interaction are. Nevertheless, health care markets obey the fundamental rules of economics, and economic analysis is essential in appraising public policy.

The ultimate output of medical care is its effect on health. This effect can only be assigned probabilities before the care is provided and is difficult to measure even after the fact. Medical care is not the only determinant of health; others include nutrition, exercise, and other life-style factors. Efficient allocation of private and public budgets to health requires equating marginal benefit and marginal cost for each of these inputs (see Marginalism).

Risk and insurance. The risk of illness naturally leads people to demand health insurance. But in the United States the demand for health insurance is distorted by the fact that employer contributions are tax-exempt compensation to employees (see Health Insurance). This implies an open-ended subsidy at the employee's marginal tax rate, including income and payroll taxes at the federal and state levels. This "tax expenditure," which does not appear in any government budget, was estimated at over $50 billion in 1990. Assuming an average marginal tax rate of 33 percent, this subsidy more than offsets the administrative expense built into insurance premiums. Consequently, the average employee is better off insuring even routine medical services.

Since 1960, third-party payment for health care has increased dramatically. The share paid directly out of pocket by consumers fell from 49 percent in 1960 to 21 percent in 1988. At the same time, public financing increased from 24.5 percent to 42.1 percent, and private health insurance increased from 22 percent to 32 percent.

Pervasive third-party payment profoundly affects the structure of the medical care industry and the quantity, cost, and quality of services offered. Because insurance companies pay a large percent of the cost of medical care, the insured consumer's point-of-purchase price is necessarily lower. If the doctor charges forty dollars and the insurance company pays 80 percent, for example, the consumer's price is only eight dollars. As in any market the quantity demanded increases when price falls.

A five-year randomized trial of alternative insurance plans for the nonelderly population conducted by the Rand Corporation found strong evidence of the responsiveness of demand to insurance coverage. Some patients in the experiment were given totally free care. Others were required to pay 95 percent of the cost of medical services, up to a stop-loss. (A stop-loss is a limit on out-of-pocket expenses. In the experiment, it was set at 5 to 15 percent of income, up to a maximum of a thousand dollars in 1976 dollars.) Beyond the stop-loss they too received free care. Total expenditures for the group given free care were 45 percent higher than for the group that paid 95 percent up to the stop-loss. Free care increased total expenditures by 23 percent relative to a plan in which patients made a 25 percent copayment up to a stop-loss. For the great majority of participants, the difference in expenditures had no measurable effect on health, whether judged by objective measures or by the patients themselves.

Far harder to measure is the effect of insurance on technological change and on the "quality" of services available. Insured consumers (or physicians on their behalf) have incentives to use any new medical service if the expected benefit exceeds their private out-of-pocket cost, which is less than the full social cost. Thus, medical technologies can be profitable even if their expected benefits are below their cost. Overinvestment in technology is reinforced by provider incentives to compete on nonprice dimensions of service in markets where consumers are insulated from prices. In recent years third-party payers have become more aggressive as cost-conscious purchasers on behalf of insured consumers (see below), but the tensions remain.

Asymmetric information. Consumers typically have less information than providers do about the risks and benefits of alternative treatments, and therefore rely on physicians to advise as well as treat them. Such mixed roles are common in many professional and other contexts. They are, however, more complex in medical care because the provider is an agent not only for the individual patient but also for the third-party payer, who in turn is ultimately the agent for policyholders/patients as a group. Each individual patient would like to consume any service that has any expected benefit at all if the out-of-pocket cost is zero. But in the long run patients as policyholders are better off if insurers control moral hazard (the increase in quantity and "quality" of services in response to insurance) because insurance premiums must ultimately rise to cover the costs.

Insurers compete by devising better ways of controlling moral hazard. Thus, devising contractual incentives for providers to make the right trade-offs between the short-run desires of individual patients and long-run insurer/policyholder interests is at the heart of the ongoing revolution in health care markets, both in forms of reimbursement and organizational structure. Preferred provider organizations (PPOs), health maintenance organizations (HMOs), and various forms of managed care give doctors incentives to control insurance-induced overutilization.

Government. Government is more pervasive in health care than in almost any other industry, though less so in the United States than in most other developed countries. Such interventions are rationalized on grounds of assuring either access or quality. Government is the largest insurer, through Medicare and Medicaid, and public hospitals act as provider of last resort for those who cannot pay for care. Licensure, accreditation, and other regulations either directly or indirectly affect entry of physicians, dentists, and other medical professionals, as well as hospitals, nursing homes, and other institutional providers. New pharmaceuticals and medical devices must first be approved by the Food and Drug Administration.

The Growth in Costs—Why, and Is It Worth It?

Health care expenditures as a percent of GNP have grown more rapidly in the United States than in other countries. How much value we get for these expenditures and whether governments should further intervene to control costs have become major issues in public debate.

The growth in real health care costs per capita, net of economy-wide inflation, can be split into three components: medical price increases (in excess of other prices); increases in volume of services per capita; and increases in intensity of resource use per unit of service. Intensity reflects changing technology, "quality," and other factors that make any given service, such as a diagnostic test, more resource-intensive than it was in the past. In practice it is virtually impossible to construct quality-adjusted and technology-adjusted price indexes that meaningfully separate pure medical price increases from increases in intensity. Moreover, even an accurate accounting for cost growth does not illuminate the underlying causes.

Nevertheless, technology appears to be the single most important factor driving health care costs currently. A standard economist's presumption, based on theory and evidence, is that technology is not introduced unless it produces benefits at least as great as the costs. This presumption does not necessarily apply to new medical technologies, however. The reason is that massive government subsidies, directly through tax-funded government insurance programs and indirectly through the tax subsidy to private health insurance, cause medical providers to use technology that consumers may value less than the cost.

Although other countries with more centralized government control over health budgets appear to have controlled costs more successfully, that does not mean that they have produced a more efficient result. In any case, reported statistics may be misleading. Efficient resource allocation requires that resources be spent on medical care as long as the marginal benefit exceeds the marginal cost. Marginal benefits are very hard to measure, but certainly include more subjective values than the crude measures of morbidity and mortality that are widely used in international comparisons.

In addition to forgone benefits, government health care systems have hidden costs. Any insurance system, public or private, must raise revenues, pay providers, control moral hazard, and bear some nondiversifiable risk. In a private insurance market such as in the United States, the costs of performing these functions can be measured by insurance overhead costs of premium collection, claims administration, and return on capital. Public monopoly insurers must also perform these functions, but their costs tend to be hidden and do not appear in health expenditure accounts. Tax financing entails deadweight costs that have been estimated at over seventeen cents per dollar raised—far higher than the 1 percent of premiums required by private insurers to collect premiums.

The use of tight physician fee schedules gives doctors incentives to reduce their own time and other resources per patient visit; patients must therefore make multiple visits to receive the same total care. But these hidden patient time costs do not appear in standard measures of health care spending.

Both economic theory and a careful review of the evidence that goes beyond simple accounting measures suggest that a government monopoly of financing and provision achieves a less efficient allocation of resources to medical care than would a well-designed private market system. The performance of the current U.S. health care system does not provide a guide to the potential functioning of a well-designed private market system. Cost and waste in the current U.S. system are unnecessarily high, because of tax and regulatory policies that impede efficient cost control by private insurers, while at the same time the system fails to provide for universal coverage (see below).

Industry Structure and Competition

Despite barriers to entry, the health care industry has become extremely competitive in recent years. This is because of the large number of firms in most market segments, a more aggressive role of public and private payers in attempting to control costs, and antitrust enforcement.

Hospitals. Prior to the eighties hospitals were paid largely on the basis of costs incurred. In 1983 Medicare introduced a system of "prospective" payment according to diagnosis-related groups (DRGs), whereby hospitals are paid a fixed fee per admission, based on the patient's diagnosis. In contrast to retrospective cost-based reimbursement, the hospital bears the marginal cost of all expenses incurred. In addition, employers and private insurers also have ceased to be passive payers; now, they actively attempt to control price and utilization through such strategies such as HMOs, selective contracting with PPOs for fixed, discounted fees, utilization review, and required second opinions. These attempts to reduce costs have been effective. Since 1981 the number of hospital admissions and the average length of stay have declined for both the over-sixty-five and under-sixty-five population, and average hospital occupancy fell from 75.9 percent in 1980 to 64.5 percent in 1988, despite a reduction in the number of beds. Changing technology has also contributed to the decline in length of stay, but aggressive buyers have certainly played a role.

The categories of customer for whom hospitals must compete have also increased. Traditionally, hospitals competed primarily for physicians who, as independent contractors with admitting privileges at multiple hospitals, have critical influence over the volume and cost of hospital admissions. Now, hospitals must also compete for contracts with third-party payers who restrict their policyholders' choice of facilities, and must market directly to patients, particularly for elective services, where patients choose the hospital. Moreover, technological advance has increased the number of surgical and major diagnostic procedures that can be performed on either an inpatient or outpatient basis. Hospitals, therefore, also compete with ambulatory surgery and diagnostic centers.

Physicians. The number of physicians active in patient care almost doubled from 237,500 in 1965 to 455,700 in 1987, or from 124 to 189 physicians per 100,000 population. This increase reflects the response of medical schools to federal subsidies introduced to increase the supply of physicians after the introduction of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965.

In competitive markets an increase in supply is expected to lead to lower prices and, hence, increased quantity. Total expenditures may increase or decrease, depending on whether demand is elastic or inelastic. Many commentators express concern that, in the medical context, more physicians means increased volume of "supplier-induced" services, rather than price reductions.

The evidence on this issue is mixed and likely to remain inconclusive. Many physicians have moved to rural areas that were previously unserved. Presumably, they would not have done so if they had unlimited ability to induce demand in cities. The increased willingness of physicians to accept alternatives to unconstrained fee-for-service payment is also consistent with increased competitive pressures. And many physicians have agreed to capitation (a fixed payment per patient per month, that puts the physician at risk for volume of services) and fixed-fee arrangements with utilization review. There is a persistent positive correlation between number of physicians per capita and frequency of physician visits or surgical procedures. While this is consistent with supplier-induced demand, it is however, also consistent with the commonsense idea that physicians tend to locate in areas where demand for their services is high.

Since the abolition of the antitrust immunity of physicians and other professions, antitrust has been applied to challenge such activities as maximum price schedules, preferred provider organizations, peer review, and denial of staff privileges. Similarly, antitrust has been applied to hospital mergers and contractual arrangements with physicians, medical supply companies, and insurers. Such cases require a delicate balancing of the need to protect against anticompetitive practice while at the same time permitting the contractual freedom needed to effectively control costs and quality in a market with pervasive insurance and asymmetric information.

Public Policy

Government intervention in the health care sector typically addresses either quality or access. Regulations to assure minimum quality can potentially enhance efficiency in markets with asymmetric information, infrequent purchase, and potential for catastrophic mistakes. But often the regulations take the form of licensing, which limits entry and therefore limits competition. For some professionals, replacing licensing with certification, so that consumers who want a minimum quality can be assured of it, might achieve quality control while interfering less with competition. Moreover, reputation and other market forces are increasingly powerful stimuli to quality (see Brand Names). As the market evolves in the direction of competition among alternative medical plans that compete on all dimensions of quality (including technology, amenities, and choice of providers) as well as price, the appropriate role of government in setting minimum quality standards should be reassessed.

Government intervention to assure access includes public insurance and government subsidies to hospitals and clinics. Economic theory generally concludes that government intervention to stimulate the consumption of particular commodities is undesirable. People will consume, without subsidy, what they regard as the optimal amount of various items. A subsidy for consuming hamburgers, for example, causes people to consume too many hamburgers relative to other goods. One exception to this rule is for goods whose consumption by some consumers confers benefits on others. If, for example, people would not get vaccinated against polio unless subsidized or required to do so, a strong case could be made for subsidizing or requiring polio vaccinations. But the great majority of health expenditures are now devoted to purely private services that benefit only the recipients of the services.

Another type of external effect, however, is often used to justify a public subsidy to health insurance for low-income individuals, rather than simply a cash transfer. Many view health care as a "merit" good. That is, people derive satisfaction from knowing that everyone has access to a minimum level of health care, and they therefore are unwilling to deny care to anyone in extreme need. Addressing this concern through private charity creates a free-rider dilemma: I have little incentive to give to the poor if I think you will take care of them. Moreover, the not-so-poor have little incentive to buy insurance if they expect to receive charity care should the need arise. In such cases government intervention can be efficient.

A strong public demand for some minimum medical safety net argues for assuring universal access to insurance, but this does not require public provision of either insurance itself or medical services. Universal access to insurance can be achieved through a system of vouchers with income-related subsidies. But subsidies may not be sufficient to assure that everyone buys coverage, unless the subsidies are set at a very high level. Subsidies high enough to induce everyone to buy insurance voluntarily would provide large benefits to those who would have bought coverage with a lower subsidy. And such subsidies would entail large dead-weight costs of raising tax revenues. Subsidies alone are therefore an inefficient means of assuring universal coverage.

If the policy objective is universal coverage, then the simplest and most efficient approach is to make coverage compulsory, with income-related tax credits if necessary to assure affordability. Placing the requirement to obtain coverage on the individual entails less distortion of labor markets than the more widely discussed alternative, of mandating that employers provide coverage for employees. Mandating that employers provide coverage is equivalent to imposing a fixed tax per worker. Because insurance is a fixed cost per worker, the implicit tax rate is higher on low-wage and part-time workers. Unless wage rates of such workers fall to offset the cost of insurance to the employer, employment opportunities must fall. The cost of employer mandates will therefore be borne largely by currently uninsured workers, many of whom are in low-wage jobs. Some costs may also fall on small employers. In either case, this approach to covering the uninsured entails unnecessarily high total costs.

By contrast, placing the requirement to obtain coverage on the individual does not preclude that employers provide insurance. Most insurance would probably continue to be obtained through employment because of the savings in administrative costs. But other sources of group insurance are more likely to develop than under the status quo, which distorts relative prices heavily in favor of providing insurance through employment. Despite the efficiency and equity arguments in favor of requiring individuals to obtain coverage, however, politicians favor employer mandates because the costs of such an approach, although higher, are largely hidden.

Friday, May 16, 2008

X-Rays

X-Rays

space placeholder.space placeholder
space placeholder. What Are X-Rays?.
space placeholder.What You See on an X-Ray.
space placeholder.More About X-Rays.
space placeholder..
space placeholder

space placeholder
space placeholder. What Are X-Rays?
space placeholder

X-rays are a form of energy that travels in waves. X-rays can enter solid objects, where they either are absorbed or continue to pass through. X-rays tend to be absorbed by denser objects but pass easily through less dense objects.

Teeth and bone are very dense, so they absorb X-rays. X-rays pass more easily through gums and cheeks. That's why cheeks and gums appear dark and without detail on a dental X-ray, but teeth show up much lighter. Restorations such as crowns and fillings, which are even denser than bone, will show up as solid, bright white areas. Dental decay and caries (cavities) will appear on an X-ray as a darker patch.

space placeholder
space placeholder.What You See on an X-Ray
space placeholder

X-ray image with problem areas labeled

Your Dental Visit: What To Expect

Your Dental Visit: What To Expect

space placeholder.space placeholder
space placeholder. Types of Dental Visits.
space placeholder. What To Tell Your Dentist.
space placeholder. The Comprehensive Examination.
space placeholder. Checkups.
space placeholder. The Gag Reflex.
space placeholder..
space placeholder

space placeholder
space placeholder. Types of Dental Visits
space placeholder

Most people are familiar with the typical dental checkup visit. If the office has a dental hygienist, he or she will clean your teeth, do an examination and sometimes take X-rays. Then the dentist will check the X-rays and your teeth for signs of decay, check your gums for changes, and check for signs of oral cancer or other diseases.

From time to time, however, your dentist should do a more thorough exam. This is called a comprehensive examination. It includes a thorough examination of your entire mouth, head and neck area. The dentist also will ask about your medical history, and you will get X-rays if indicated.

A comprehensive examination likely will be done the first time you visit a dental office. Even if you have had regular care under another dentist, your new dentist will want to become familiar with your health. This will allow him or her to notice changes or problems more easily during future visits.

Some activities are standard for a checkup or comprehensive exam, but dentists and hygienists have their own style and skills. If your dentist doesn't do everything listed here, that doesn't necessarily mean he or she isn't doing a good job. If you are concerned, ask why certain things are left out or why others are included.

The order in which things are done may vary as well. And it doesn't all have to be done at every visit.

An important part of every visit is updating your medical history. Your dentist will want to know if you've had any changes in your health or your medicines since your last visit.

Mention everything about your health, even if you don't think it relates to your mouth. Many diseases can have significant effects on your mouth and teeth. Researchers continue to discover ways in which oral health is related to overall health. For example, people with diabetes are at a higher risk of developing periodontal disease. Research also suggests that periodontal infection can affect your blood sugar levels and make your diabetes harder to control. Other health conditions may require your dentist to change the type of anesthesia given.

Bring a list of all medicines you take, with dosages. Some medicines cause dry mouth, which can increase the risk of cavities. Your dentist also will want to check that any drug he or she prescribes doesn't interact with drugs you are already taking.

space placeholder
space placeholder. What To Tell Your Dentist
space placeholder

Your dentist needs to know everything that may help him or her diagnose problems or treat you appropriately. Tell your dentist:

  • Your fears — Many people have fears of the dentist that go back to childhood. Pain control and treatment techniques change constantly. The things you fear most may not exist any longer, or there may be new and improved ways of dealing with them. If you fear you have a particular disease or condition, let your dentist know. He or she can look for signs and either diagnose the problem or set your mind at ease. Often, just talking about your fears will take some of the edge off.


  • Your overall health — Tell your dentist if you've been diagnosed with any diseases or are taking any new medicines. It is important to tell your dentist about all medicines you take. This includes those that have been prescribed by your physician and over-the-counter medicines. Even diseases that seem to be unrelated to the mouth may require a different approach to dental treatments or prevention.


  • Your dental health — If you think you have a new cavity, if your teeth have become sensitive or if you feel lumps inside your mouth, tell your dentist before the examination starts. Don't wait to see if the dentist catches it or silently hope the dentist misses it. By telling your dentist your symptoms, you may help him or her make an early diagnosis.
space placeholder
space placeholder. The Comprehensive Examination
space placeholder

During a comprehensive examination, your dentist will look at much more than just your teeth. He or she will check other areas inside and outside your mouth for signs of disease or other problems. The comprehensive exam likely will include these evaluations:

Head and neck — Your dentist will check your head and neck, your temporomandibular (jaw) joint, your salivary glands, and lymph nodes in your neck area.

He or she will look at your face, neck and lips to make sure there are no unusual swellings, lip dryness, bleeding or other abnormalities that need to be checked further.

Your temporomandibular joint, often called the TMJ, is the joint that guides your lower jaw when you open your mouth. To see if your temporomandibular joint is working properly, your dentist will ask you to open and close your mouth and to move your lower jaw from side to side. You will be asked if you have had any pain or soreness in the joint. Your dentist may touch the joint while you open and close your mouth to feel for hitches or catches in movement that may indicate problems.

Your dentist will touch salivary glands and lymph nodes in your neck area to feel for swelling or tenderness that may indicate infection or disease.

Soft tissue — The soft tissues of the mouth include the tongue, the inside of the lips and cheeks, and the floor and roof of the mouth. Your dentist will look at these areas to check for spots, cuts, swellings, growths or other abnormal areas that may indicate problems with oral health.

Periodontal — A periodontal examination involves checking the gums and supporting structures of the teeth. First, your dentist will look at the gums for signs of redness or puffiness and may poke them gently to see how easily they bleed. These symptoms may indicate gum disease. Your dentist may use a special probe to measure the depth of the pockets between your teeth and your gums. Pockets deeper than 3 millimeters often indicate periodontal disease. If your dentist determines that you have periodontal disease, he or she may refer you to a periodontist. This is a specialist who treats diseases of the gums.

Occlusion — Your dentist may check how well your teeth fit together by examining your bite. First, you will be asked to bite naturally. If the teeth don't seem to fit together properly, your dentist may do further checks by having you bite down on special wax or paper. Your teeth make an impression in the wax that can help show how your teeth meet. The paper makes temporary marks on your teeth that show where your teeth come together.

Clinical examination of teeth — Your dentist will check for decay by looking at every tooth surface (using a mirror to see the back sides of teeth). He or she also will poke your teeth with a tool called an explorer to detect cavities. Decayed tooth enamel is softer than healthy enamel. If you have fillings, permanent bridges, crowns or other restorations, your dentist will check to make certain that they remain whole and sound and that the teeth around them have no sign of decay.

X-rays — X-rays, also called radiographs, will be taken to help your dentist look for decay (cavities) or other oral health problems that cannot be seen during the clinical exam. X-rays also provide the best way for the dentist to see a need for root canal treatment, or bone loss that may indicate advanced gum disease.

space placeholder
space placeholder. Checkups
space placeholder

During a checkup visit, you sometimes will see two professionals — your dentist and the dental hygienist if the office has a hygienist on staff. The hygienist typically will check your gums and teeth, clean and polish your teeth, and talk to you about caring for your teeth and gums properly at home. Your dentist also may do a clinical examination, diagnose problems and recommend treatments. Here's what to expect:

Cleaning — The purpose of a professional dental cleaning is to remove the hard calculus (also called tartar) from above and just below the gum line. Brushing and flossing at home removes plaque. Only dental instruments can remove calculus. Some dental hygienists use ultrasonic instruments to blast away the larger chunks of tartar. They follow up with hand instruments to thoroughly clean the teeth. Other hygienists use only hand instruments.

Polishing — After the calculus is removed, the crowns of your teeth (the parts that show) may be polished to remove plaque and surface stains. Typically, but not always, an abrasive substance is applied to the teeth with a small rotating rubber cup or brush. This helps to scrub away stains. The polishing substance will feel gritty in your mouth. You will be given a chance to rinse periodically.

Prevention — The hygienist may offer instructions for oral care at home based on the results of the exam. He or she may demonstrate how to brush and floss properly. Sometimes, the hygienist will teach you to use a disclosing agent to test your brushing ability. A disclosing agent is a red solution or tablet that is applied to the teeth or chewed. The agent attaches to plaque and colors it to make it visible. Then you brush your teeth. You'll be able to see any plaque that you missed. Not all dentists and hygienists recommend disclosing agents because they can be tricky to use. For example, they may highlight some areas of plaque that can be removed only by professional polishing. They may also stain tooth-colored fillings. Some experts recommend using a disclosing agent only at the dentist's office, and only if the hygienist is prepared to polish any remaining red color off the teeth afterward. Other dental experts, however, believe that disclosing agents for some patients are a useful tool for improving oral hygiene practices and recommend their use at home.

X-rays — X-rays may or may not be taken during your checkup. In the past, many dentists took X-rays at every checkup. But the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) currently says that X-rays do not always need to be taken at every visit. Although dental X-rays are safe, the FDA says unnecessary exposure should be limited because the effects of radiation add up over time. People also are exposed to radiation from numerous other sources. Some people may be able to go as long as two years between X-rays. Others may need them every few months. Your dentist will consider the results of your clinical examination, your dental history and your individual risk for developing cavities before deciding if you need X-rays during your check-up visit. If you are seeing a new dentist for the first time, ask for a copy of your X-rays from your former dentist to avoid repeating X-rays unnecessarily.

Treatment recommendations — If your dentist finds any problems, he or she will recommend steps to fix them. These may include a referral to a specialist (such as a periodontist or orthodontist). You also may need further tests for diagnosis. You may have to return to the dentist for a filling or more intensive periodontal cleanings.

space placeholder
space placeholder. The Gag Reflex
space placeholder

The gag reflex, located on the back wall of the throat, helps keep objects from going down your windpipe. If you have ever put your fingers too far back in your mouth and felt like gagging or throwing up, you've discovered the gag reflex. Some people have a very sensitive gag reflex. This makes going to the dentist very difficult.

If you are one of these people, talk with your dentist about your concerns. Sometimes, a new dentist or hygienist may place instruments in a sensitive spot, touching the soft palate (the entrance to your throat). If you warn the dentist or hygienist ahead of time, they should be able to avoid certain sensitive areas.

It's also possible that something you are doing makes the problem worse. For example, some patients draw their tongue back to give the dentist room to work, but they end up gagging themselves. You and your dentist or hygienist can work together to find ways to avoid gagging movements.

Distraction may also work. Patients who are highly concerned about gagging become tense in the chair. Tension can heighten the sensitivity. Bring a portable music device and listen to music, practice meditation or focus on trying to keep your feet elevated one inch off the chair. These kinds of distractions can help you keep your mind off your throat.